The Macroeconomic Effects of Eliminating Automatic Reductions to Discretionary Spending Caps
CBO has analyzed the macroeconomic effects of eliminating automatic reductions in discretionary spending caps established under the Budget Control Act of 2011 for fiscal years 2016 and 2017.
Summary
Letter to the Honorable Bernard Sanders
The Budget Control Act of 2011 created caps on discretionary budget authority for each year through 2021. That act also provided for automatic reductions in those caps that would be triggered under certain conditions. At your request, the Congressional Budget Office has analyzed the macroeconomic effects of eliminating those automatic reductions for fiscal years 2016 and 2017.
Fully eliminating the reductions would allow for an increase in appropriations of $90 billion in 2016 and $91 billion in 2017. According to CBO’s estimates, such an increase would raise total outlays above what is projected under current law by $53 billion in fiscal year 2016, $76 billion in fiscal year 2017, $30 billion in fiscal year 2018, and a cumulative $19 billion in later years.
Those changes in spending would have the following macroeconomic effects:
- Over the course of calendar year 2016, on average, CBO estimates that the spending changes would make real (inflation-adjusted) gross domestic product (GDP) 0.4 percent larger than projected under current law. They would also increase full-time-equivalent employment by 0.5 million. Those effects would result chiefly from two partly offsetting forces. First, the increase in federal spending would lead to more aggregate demand than under current law. Second, monetary policy would tighten slightly in response to the slightly stronger economic growth and to the slight increase in inflationary pressure that would result. That tighter monetary policy would begin to dampen the positive effects on output and employment.
- Over the course of calendar year 2017, on average, CBO estimates that the spending changes would make real GDP 0.2 percent larger than projected under current law. They would also increase full-time-equivalent employment by 0.3 million. Those effects would result from three partly offsetting forces. First, the increase in federal spending would further boost aggregate demand, as in 2016, CBO estimates. Second, the delayed effects of the slightly tighter monetary policy in 2016, along with additional tightening in 2017, would further dampen the positive effects on output and employment. Third, the increased borrowing by the federal government that the spending increases would bring about would start to gradually reduce—or crowd out—private investment in productive capital because the portion of people’s savings used to buy government securities would not be available to finance private investment. On balance, the three forces would result in smaller increases in real GDP and employment in 2017 than in 2016.
Those figures represent CBO’s central estimates, which correspond to the assumption that key parameters of economic behavior (in particular, the extent to which higher federal spending boosts aggregate demand in the short term) equal the midpoints of the ranges used by CBO for those parameters. The ranges suggest that if the automatic reductions to the discretionary caps were fully eliminated, real GDP could be 0.1 percent to 0.6 percent higher in calendar year 2016, and 0.1 percent to 0.4 percent higher in calendar year 2017, than projected under current law. The ranges also suggest that full-time-equivalent employment could be 0.2 million to 0.8 million higher in calendar year 2016, and 0.1 million to 0.6 million higher in calendar year 2017, than projected under current law.
Although eliminating the reductions to the spending caps for fiscal years 2016 and 2017 would increase output and employment over the next few years, the resulting increases in federal deficits would, in the longer term, make the nation’s output and income lower than they would be otherwise.